Book review: Inequality, Development, and Growth (Routledge, 2011)
May 27, 2011
Irene van Staveren
Review of Inequality, Development, and Growth
, edited by Günseli Berik, Yana van der Meulen Rogers, and Stephanie Seguino. London: Routledge, 2011, 361 pp. ISBN13: 978-0-415-59944-3 (hbk), ISBN13: 978-0-415-60994-4 (pbk).
This volume is a flagship for feminist macroeconomics and was first published as a special issue of the journal Feminist Economics in 2009. Its major contribution to the study of inequality and growth is that it follows a two-sided approach to the relationship between these two phenomena. The book examines not only the effect of macroeconomic policies and economic growth on inequalities but also as the effects of inequality on growth. The volume presents a wide diversity of theories, methods, country studies and levels of integration by an equally wide diversity of authors, male and female, and from the developed as well as the developing world.
For example, gender inequality in education leads to relative over-investment in less talented men and under-investment in able women, lowering aggregate productivity levels in the economy. This mechanism is empirically supported in the chapter by Klasen and Lamanna, using data of 93 countries overt the period 1960-2000. The authors show that in regions with high gender inequality in education growth is between 0.1 and 1.7 percentage points lower than in East Asia, where gender inequality in education is much smaller. In addition, the chapter by Busse and Nunnenkamp shows, with a large data set of FDI on middle income developing countries, that there is a positive relationship between gender equality in education and FDI inflows. Hence, the volume provides empirical support for the feminist viewpoint that gender equality in education is good for growth and development. Obviously, the editors note, the empirical studies have limitations and more detailed analysis is necessary.
Finally, the editors argue for policies toward equitable development. The chapter by Koopmans is a good example for the need of such policies, in this case on trade regulation. Koopmans convincingly shows that the current food crisis in the Senegal River Valley can only be addressed by providing access to technology and securing women’s land rights. But she also recognizes that such measures will remain ineffective as long as there are no import constraints allowed for products that compete with locally produced food crops that are key to subsistence – crops that are largely produced by women. Hence, the chapter indicates that trade liberalization, in particular without land rights for women, tends to undermine food security and agricultural growth in the poorest and most vulnerable regions of the world. Gender inequality is here not only an effect of liberalization but also a cause of the lack of success of trade liberalization. The chapter indicates that both domestic policies towards strengthening women’s land rights and access to technology are important, as well as trade regulation to enable food production in fertile but vulnerable regions of the world.
The remainder of my review will briefly go into two quite different chapters of the book. In a chapter on the growing income inequality in China, Dong, Dong and Li focus on the retrenchment of public sector jobs, particularly since 1995, and the disproportionate job losses by women in the public sector because of this. To analyze the impact of employment and earnings of married women on household income distribution, the authors use the coefficient of variation as a summary measure of the level of inequality in three household surveys. The data show that women’s employment has decreased between 1995 and 2002 from 92% to 75%. But there is also increasing inequality among women, which they show by calculating the ratio of employment and earnings of women of the first to the fifth quintile of their husbands’ earnings. The ratios show a decline in the employment ratio of poorer over richer women from 102% in 1988 to 89% in 2002, and in the earnings ratio from 59% to 47%. The decomposition and simulation results of their model indicate that, first, women’s employment had an equalizing effect on the household income distribution. Second, however, the decline in women’s employment ratio since 1995 has contributed to the rising income inequality. The income inequality in women’s earnings has contributed importantly to the increased household income inequality. This inequality is comparable to, or even stronger than the effect of men’s income inequality on household income inequality in China since 1995. In my view, this chapter provides an important contribution to understanding the linkages between inequality and growth in China. First, because it shows that the assumption of a socialist legacy for equal pay for men and women no longer holds true. Second, because it points out that the rising income inequality in China is juts as much, or perhaps even more, driven by increasing gender inequalities in employment and wages, as it is by inequalities in class. These findings provide support for the hypothesis that with market liberalization, old patriarchal values seem to have been freed-up as well in China.
The second and last chapter that I like to discuss here is by Siddiqui who constructs a CGE model form Pakistan to test whether men and women share equally in the effects of trade liberalization. Before the CGE can be constructed, data on intra-household differences need to be collected. Using available socio-economic data for Pakistan, the author finds that the consumption of basic needs as well as basic capabilities (education, health) are unequally distributed over men and women, and more so in poorer households. Next, the author has constructed a gender-disaggregated SAM including time-use data on unpaid work. The SAM shows that whereas men spend 50% of their time on market work, 10% on unpaid work and 40% on leisure, women spend 33% on market work, 47% on unpaid work and 20% on leisure. This indicates that women suffer more than men from time poverty. The CGE has six blocks of equations: income and savings, production, demand, prices, trade, and equilibrium. Gender rigidities are included through a low elasticity of substitution (0.3) between the labour of men and women. The nonmarket sectors of social reproduction (unpaid work) and leisure behave like market sectors and produce goods that are consumed by the households themselves. Total household income is the sum of receipts from the market and the nonmarket economy. The simulation exercise is for a 50% revenue neutral tariff reduction. The model simulation leads to the following results. The trade liberalization leads to a net increase in women’s employment in industry, driven by the textile sector, and net decrease of male employment in the industry sector. For both women and men employment declines in agriculture and services so that the total employment effect is negative, 0.7% for women and 0.4% for men. Female leisure declines, or it increases less than for men, depending on the type of household. The poorest households experience the strongest income decline due to falling wage rates for unskilled labour. Women’s consumption is more affected than men’s but not in rich households. Poverty declines on average by 0.3% but not for all households, whereas relative poverty among women increases slightly due to an increase in the share of women among the poor. Time poverty increases for women, not for men. In conclusion: the chapter demonstrates how a gender-aware CGE model can capture a variety of positive and negative gender (equality) effects of trade liberalization, beyond employment and wages. This is an important contribution of feminist economic analysis to trade evaluation studies, even though it has its shortcomings, such as the assumption that the nonmarket sector behaves similarly as the market sector, ignoring informal institutions.
In conclusion, the volume features state of the art research in feminist macroeconomics. The wide variety of approaches, however, may lead some readers, who are comfortable with the mainstream literature on inequality and growth, to get a bit overwhelmed by the wide diversity of theory, method, and level of analysis that this collection inevitably brings. In my view, the quality of the volume should keep all readers interested and hopefully motivated to use some of the insights in their own research which will enrich analyses of inequality and growth.
Comments